'Why did I say 'yes' to speak here?' by Malcolm Gladwell

Delivered by Malcolm Gladwell at Google Zeitgeist in 2013

 

Malcolm Gladwell has an incredible ability to keep a giant room full of people pin-drop silent for long periods of time. How does he do it? Does he yell or scream or swear? Does he have flashy slides or dance around the stage? No. None of these things! And yet … he pulls off magic trick after magic trick by distilling complex topics into simple stories and packaging them without pomp into wonderfully acrobatic and accessible ways. This somewhat lesser known speech he gave in 2013 at Google offers great lessons on connecting with an audience, raising interest, and captivating a room. The title is a little misleading as it’s actually about something he calls “Elite Institution Cognitive Disorder” which has a wonderfully simple takeaway along the lines of ‘find small ponds where you can be a big fish.’ Hope you enjoy and, for more of Malcolm, you can check out our 3 Books conversation, listen to Revisionist History, or read Bomber Mafia.

 

Speech:

It's a real pleasure to be here. 

I’m, I was -- I'm acutely conscious to the fact as I listened, uh, both to our previous speaker, and also the ones before, that everyone has been speaking about very consequential and high-minded things this morning, and I'm not going to do that at all.

Um, in fact, I intend to give what I am sure will be the most solipsistic talk ever at a Google Zeitgeist. I simply want to talk about why on earth I decided to, uh, say yes and come here.

Um, here's the situation.

I'm a writer.

Part of what I do to make my living is I go and give speeches at conferences like this. And I, I get paid, right? As one would. And, um, it's that money that I use to, to make my living.

So how much is Google paying me for this?

Zero.

A company with, what? Fifty billion dollars in the bank and they don't have a dime for poor little old Malcolm. Now, we could talk at length about what this says about Google, but I — that's not what interests me.

What interests me is what that says about me.

Why on earth would I say yes … under such a circumstance?

Why -- you know, I’m busy. My time is really valuable. Why did I fly all the way out here across the country, to give away my intellectual property for free? In fact, it wasn't even free! I had to print out my speech this morning in the Business Center. And, um, this is, uh, this is the bill, it cost me $9.87.

It’s costing me to be here.

(laughter)

Now, you can say that I came here because there are all kinds of interesting people here which is true. But, it’s, and you know I don't mean to cast any aspersions on any of you, but my life is lousy with interesting people. I got more interesting people than I know what to — so, you could say maybe I should have come here, I should come here because I can make contacts that will help me, you know, in the business world.

I'm not in the business world.

I don't need to meet a VC. I work out of my apartment. If I want to renovate my kitchen, I’ll just go to the bank for a loan.

There's no -- it doesn't make any sense, in other words, for me to be here.

So why did I say yes?

Well, the answer is that this conference is run by Google, one of the most prestigious and successful companies in the world. I would not have agreed to speak for free at a Yahoo conference, would I?

(laughter)

So, in other words, my decision to do something that is not in my best interest was caused by my association with an elite institution.

And this is what I want to talk about today.

It’s an argument that I make in my new book David and Goliath, which — in further proof of how baffling my decision was to come here — is not available for sale at this conference.

I like to call this problem Elite Institution Cognitive Disorder or EICD.

And it is simply that elite institutions screw us up in all kinds of ways that we're not always conscious of. And since the theme of this morning's session is "Imagine a Better World," I want to try and imagine what the world would look like if we freed ourselves of the scourge of EICD.

So I am going to give you a couple of examples of EICD in action.

But let me start with the very thorny question of science and math, science and math education in this country. STEM, as we call it. We have a problem in turning out enough science and math [college] graduates, right? In this country. And it’s not for lack of interest, by the way, among high school seniors. Lots and lots and lots of high school seniors want to get science and math degrees, but approximately half of them drop out by the end of their second year.

So we have a persistence problem in science and math education in this country.

So the question is why?

Why do so many kids drop out?

Well, the obvious answer is that science and math are really hard and you need to have a certain level of cognitive ability to master those subjects and we don't have enough smart kids, right?

So, if you, if that's true, if science and math education is a function of -- we should be able to see in the statistics that persistence is a function of your cognitive ability.

So let's take a look.

By the way, this is the first time in my life I have ever used Powerpoint.

This is like a fantastic moment for me.

I feel like I have finally joined the 20th century.

It is really … kind of amazing.

(screen turns on)

Oh, wow.

(laughter)

Okay.

So this is -- I've just chosen Hartwick College as a proxy for American colleges for totally random reasons. Hartwick is a small liberal arts college in upstate New York. What we have [onscreen] here is a distribution of math SAT scores among the people who are intending to major in science and math.

What you can see is that there is quite a wide range of native math ability among the kids entering the freshmen STEM programs at Hartwick.

Right?

So what do we see when we look at who ends up graduating with a STEM degree? What we see is that at Hartwick College, the kids in the top third, the top third SAT scores, end up getting well over half of the STEM degrees and the kids with the bottom scores end up getting very few of the STEM degrees. Those kids over there are dropping out like flies.

This would seem to suggest that our original hypothesis, that persistence is a function of cognitive ability is true. And this would also -- we can also go further. We can say if this hypothesis is true, as we go to more and more selective institutions, we should see a very different pattern of persistence. We should see less kids dropping out because the kids are all smarter.

Right?

So let's go to Harvard.

These numbers are a few years old.

But at Harvard, you can see that the bottom third of math SAT scores among kids doing science and math are equal to the top third at Hartwick. The dumb students at Harvard are as smart as the smart students at Hartwick. So you would think everybody at Harvard should be getting a math and science degree, right? Why would they drop out? Everyone is so smart.

What do we see?

Oh, dear.

What we see is the exact same pattern at Harvard that we saw at Hartwick. The smart kids — the top kids — are getting all the degrees. The kids at the bottom aren't getting any degrees. They are dropping out like flies, right? Even though these kids are brilliant.

Right?

So what's happening?

Well, clearly what we're seeing here is that persistence in science and math is not simply a function of your cognitive ability. It's a function of your relative standing in your class. It is a function of your class rank, right?

Those kids who are really, really brilliant don't get their math degree not because -- not as a function of their IQ but as a function of where they are in their class. And, by the way, if you look at any college you want, you will always see, regardless of the level of cognitive ability among the students, you will always see the same pattern.

The kids who get the science and math degrees are the ones in the top of their class. And the kids in the bottom of their class never do.

So the name given for this phenomenon amongst psychologists is relative deprivation theory. And it describes this exceedingly robust phenomenon which says that as human beings we do not form our self-assessments based on our standing in the world. We form our self-assessments based on our standing in our immediate circle, on those in the same boat as ourselves, right?

So a classic example of relative deprivation theory is which kind of country -- which countries have the highest suicide rates? Happy countries or unhappy countries?

And the answer is happy countries.

If you are morbidly depressed in a country where everyone else is really unhappy, you don't feel that unhappy.

Right?

You are not comparing yourself to the universe -- the whole universe of people out there. No. You are comparing yourself to your neighbors and the kids at school and they are unhappy too, so you’re sort of fine.

But if you are morbidly depressed in a country where everyone is jumping up and down for joy, you are really depressed, right? That is a very, very, very profoundly serious place to be and so, as a result, you get that sad outcome more often.

So what's happening at Harvard then?

The kid in the bottom third of his class at Harvard does not say rationally: “I'm in the 99.99th percentile of all students in the world when it comes to native math ability”, even though that's true. What that kid says is, “That kid over there, Johnny over there, is getting all the answers right and I'm not. I feel like I'm really stupid and I can't handle math so I’m going to drop out, get a Fine Arts degree, move to Brooklyn, work, make $15,000 a year, and break my parents' heart.”, right?

(laughs)

So what is the implication of this?

The implication of this is that if you want to get a science and math degree, don't go to Harvard, right?

In fact, we can run the numbers on this.

Mitchell Chang at UCLA recently did the numbers and he says, as a rule of thumb, your odds of graduating — successfully getting a science and math degree — fall by two percentage points for every ten point increase in the average SAT score of your peers.

So if you’re a kid and you have a choice between Harvard and University of Maryland, and University of Maryland is your safety. University of Maryland has 150 -- on average SAT scores are 150 points lower at Maryland. That means your chance of graduating with a STEM degree from Maryland is 30% higher than it would be at Harvard.

Right?

Now -- so if you choose to go to Harvard and not Maryland, you are taking an enormous gamble. You are essentially saying “This STEM degree,” -- by the way, the most valuable commodity any college graduate could have in today's economy — “I am going to take a 30% gamble in my chances of getting that degree just so I can put Harvard on my resume.”

Is that worth it?

I don't think so. Right?

But how many kids, given a choice between Harvard and Maryland, choose Maryland?

Not that many.

Why?

EICD.

Now, why does EICD persist if it is so plainly irrational?

Well, I think it is because as human beings, we dramatically underestimate the costs of being at the bottom of a hierarchy. 

Let me give you another really remarkable example of this.

This is from a paper that was, just came out from a guy named, two economists, guy named John Connelly and Allie Sundy -- Allie Under, rather. They looked at graduates of PhD programs, economics PhD programs at American universities. And what they were interested in was “What is the publication record of these graduates in the six years after they took an academic position?”

So as you know, the principal way by which we evaluate economists is how often and how well do they publish. So what these guys did is they did a little algorithm, took the top economics journals, and weighted them according to their level of prestige, and came up with a number of how many -- your score after six years of graduation.

So we get this chart here.

What you can see, first of all, look at the 99th percentile. So what this says is, the kids who are in the 99th percentile of their PhD program at Harvard, MIT, Yale, Princeton, Columbia, Stanford, Chicago -- the 99th percentile, that's what they publish.

The Harvard students publish 4.31 journal articles in their first six years after graduation. That's amazing. Right?

Astounding number.

Same with M.I.T at 4.73.

All the way down the list.

What we see here is that the best students at the very best schools are extraordinary, and that comes as no surprise. You just saw Larry Summers here. I don't know where he went. Larry Summers, that's Larry Summers, right?

Brilliant. Genius. We knew that.

Let's look at the 85th percentile.

Now, the 85th percentile at these schools, these are schools that might take two dozen PhD students every year. So if you're in the 85th percentile in the MIT economics program, you're the fifth or sixth best student in your class. That's really smart, okay?

The 85th percent student at MIT -- or at Harvard, let's do Harvard — publishes basically one paper in their first six years versus 4.31 in the top student. So the gap between one and five is enormous, right? It is 5X.

Now, let's go down to the 55th percentile at Harvard. So the 55th percentile at Harvard is the -- let's say, the, uh, 12th best person at the greatest economics program in the world. They could arguably say they are one of the 20-top PhD economic students in the world, right?

Look what their publication rate.

0.07.

Basically they're not publishing at all.

By any standard by which we judge academic economists, these people are complete failures, right?

Now, I've picked lousy schools.

And I've started with Toronto, which is where I went to school. So this is a little masochistic moment where I basically confess to how paltry my academic pedigree is. I have also picked B.U. and then I have also picked -- non-top 30 here is simply all the schools that are so terrible I can't bring myself to name them.

So we've aggregated them all so these are schools that if your child -- anyone in this room, if your child said they were going to go to one of these schools, you would weep, okay?

What do we see here?

What we see here is that the 99th percentile at these lousy schools publish more than everyone at the top schools except for the 99th percentile, right? Do you see that?

Look at Toronto, 3.13. The only people who publish more than the top student at Toronto are the top students at those top seven schools. The top student at Boston is publishing three times more than the 80th percentile student at Harvard.

What does this tell us?

Well, it tells us that -- oh, before I get there -- the guys who did this study, having done the study, were so stunned at what they were seeing that they end their article with this whole thing about what on earth is going on with Harvard?

Here's a school which is collecting the most brilliant, the most accomplished, probably the best-looking graduate students in economics -- I can't imagine the bar is that high -- but, nonetheless, it presumably is a selection criteria. They gather them all together and, yet, everyone, except for the very, very best students, is basically a flop.

And they say, I'm quoting them, “Why is it that the majority of these successful applicants who are winners and did all the right things up to the time they applied to graduate school became so unimpressive after they are trained?”

Are we -- and this is a moment of genuine distress on the part of these two economists -- are we failing the students or are they failing us?

No one's failing anyone!

What you're just seeing is relative deprivation in action, right?

When it comes to confidence and motivation and self-efficacy, the things that really matter when it comes to making your way in the world, relative position matters more than absolute position. The 80th percentile student at Harvard looks at those kids who are smarter than him and says, "I can't do it."

The number one student at Missouri says, "Wow, I am lord of the manor. I am going to go out and conquer the world!"

Right?

So what does it mean?

Well, what it means, what it means first of all, when it comes to hiring, it means you should hire on the basis of class rank. And you should be completely indifferent to the institution attended by the applicant. In fact, we should have a ‘don't ask, don't tell’ policy, for the name of your undergraduate institution.

(laughter)

It's hurting us to know that. Doesn't help us.

And when you hear some institution, some fabulous Wall Street investment bank, some university say, "We only hire from the top schools," you should say, "You moron!"

(laughter)

No, you don't want to hire from only the best schools.

You want to hire from the top students from any school under the sun.

And it also means that when it comes -- if you have kids going to college — when it comes to choosing your undergraduate institution, you should never go to the best institution you get into — never!

Go to your second or your third choice.

Go to the place where you're guaranteed to be in the top part of your class.

So why don't we do that?

Well, why did I come here when it was profoundly in my self-interest not to, right?

Because when we have an opportunity to join elite institutions, we are so enormously flattered and pleased with ourselves that we do things that are irrational.

Thank you.

(Applause)

 

 

Sign Up for a Dose of Inspiration:

Every other week, I send an email out with one of my favorite speeches, essays or poems. No ads, no sponsors, no spam, and nothing for sale. Just a dose of inspiration or beauty!

Click here to sign up.